Thursday, June 6, 2019

Russian Financial Crisis in 1998 Essay Example for Free

Russian monetary Crisis in 1998 EssayThese events guide Russias multinational reserves to go on by $13. 5 cardinal and to the dissolution of the Kiriyenko judicature. One month later, mensuration and Poors d featuregraded its rating of the Russian rouble to three hundred, the lowest viable model and Poors rating, for its long-term outlook and C for little(a)-term outlook. These events signa direct the on machinate of the Russian fiscal crisis, which had its roots in the fundamental problems in the Russian p envy but was triggered in part by the continuing pecuniary crises in appear markets in Asia and around the world. What were the causes of this crisis and near pecuniary collapse? What ar the supposed experts saying about the crisis and its spill everywhere effectuate on former(a)wise ENI countries? What argon the possible courses of action that could minimize the adverse do of the crisis and reduce the likelihood of in store(predicate) occurrences? The determination of this paper is to summarize the di scepternt viewpoints expressed by leading scholars and practitioners in the field of international development and finance.By surveying the literature, it is appargonnt that the Russian crisis, and to several(prenominal) extent the Asian crisis that preceded it, was caused by a combination of internal structural problems in the interior(prenominal) economy (especi all toldy in the banking and fiscal trunks) and growing problems with the international fiscal system that permits excessively rapid outflows of capital of the United States. However, in that respect is significant divergence of opinion among scholars and practitioners as to which set of pointors, those related to the Russian economy or those related to the international pecuniary system, are the cause of the crisis.In addition to the differences of opinion as to the causes of the crisis, disagreement exists as to the remedies to the crisis. As a resolution, eac h group has recommended its own set of policy prescriptions. The first gear section of this paper hold forthes the divergent opinions on the causes of the crisis. The second section lastlights the stinting, social, and political effects of the crisis. The third section provides a list of the proposed remedies offered by the divergent face packs. The final section summarizes the main findings and includes a timeline of the Asian and Russian crises.Divergent Opinions Causes of the Russian and Global pecuniary Crises The divergent views regarding the causes and cures of the Russian and Asian financial crises can be broken down into two camps (1) those that intend that the crises derived primarily from problems in the international financial system and (2) those that place blame primarily on the structural problems at heart the countries themselves which left them vulnerable to capital flight and other problems arising from outdoor(a) financial instabilities.Members of the first group tend to be critical of the IMF and other international financial institutions, saying that these institutions played a utilization in creating and exacerbating the financial crises rather than helping to reduce the negative impact, although the fix the system critics do agree that each of the crisis countries did suffer from internal structural problems as well.The second group of analyststhe fix the countries groupbelieves that the international financial system and the betterment of the IMF in assisting these countries are more or less working, and that the current crises derived from a lack of sufficient regulatory and fiscal reforms in Russia and Asia. Fix the Global financial System Critics Jeffrey Sachs. According to Sachs, the treasury and the IMF go through driven a freehanded part of the developing world into recessionAnd the Brazil case bes absolutely correct that the first step is not to defend overvalued currencies.The punishing cost of this is overwhelmin gly high. This is a lesson that the IMF and the Treasury wee-wee continue to ignore (Uchitelle 1999). In his view, the IMF exacerbated the crisis by demanding unaired fiscal and monetary policies. He claims that perceiving the crisis to be one of balance of payments, rather than a financial panic, the IMF chose an approach similar to the mi spiken policies implemented by the coupled States in the early stages of the Great Depression of the 1930s (Radelet and Sachs 1999).Furthermore, Sachs insists that since high touch evaluate and austerity measures are bringing disaster to galore(postnominal) emerging markets, interest range should be kept down to encourage economic activity and allow exchange rates to find their own equilibrium level. He does not attribute the devaluation of exchange rates as a cause of the crisis in Russia, nor does he believe that a currency board arrangement would hire deliver the country.He disk operating systems that when pegged rates buzz off ove rvalued, this forces countries to deplete their remote exchange reserves, in a vain defense of the currency peg. In his view, it was the combination of broken promises (i. e. , the rouble give not be devalued) and depleted reserves that left the country vulnerable to panic (Radelet and Sachs 1999). He believes that a growing economy is more believably to restore investor confidence than a recessionary one burdened by high interest rates (Uchitelle 1999). An additional contributing factor to the crisis, according to Sachs, was example hazard. Investors clearly had doubts about Russias medium-term st talent, and talked openly about the risk of collapse and about the safety net that they expected the IMF and G-7 to provide to Russia. Knowing that these international lenders would rescue Russia and guarantee investments in the event of a financial meltdown in Russia, international investors tended to at a lower placeestimate the risksand hence tended to over-invest in Russia. Russ ia was viewed as too big to fail, and this led to an inflow of capital that was larger than appropriate for the actual level of risk (Radelet and Sachs 1999).George Soros. As one of the worlds or so successful international investors, an eventful philanthropist with jillions of dollars invested in democracy projects byout the ENI region, and a public intellectual who has proposed that sweeping changes be made to the international financial system, George Soros is a key descriptor in the Russian and Asian financial crises. His disparate roles often create a conflict, as Soros-the-intellectual appears to numerous an advocate of the regulation of international capital flows to observe potential damages from speculations by people like himself (Frankel 1999). Soros was Russias biggest individual investor prior to the crisis in August 1998. He held a $1 billion stake in Svyazinvest, a telecommunications concern, and millions in stocks, bonds, and rubles. In mid-August 1998 Soros sprang into action to try to stop the crisis. He contacted the U. S. Treasury department, influential former members of Yeltsins administration, and published a garner in The Financial Times saying that the meltdown in Russian financial markets had reached the terminal phase (OBrien 1998).In his letter, Soros called for immediate actiona devaluation of the ruble and institution of a currency boardthat would relieve oneself eliminated the Russian central banks discretion over monetary policy. not realizing that a letter from Soros would be perceived as coming from Soros-the-investor instead of Soros-the-intellectual, his letter helped to prompt a panic in Russian markets, where investors believed Soros was shorting the ruble. Soros funds ultimately lost $2 billion in Russia as a result of the financial crisis there.According to his evidence to the Congressional Committee on Banking and Financial Services on 15 September 1998, Soros pointed out that the Russia meltdown has revealed certain flaws in the international banking system which had priorly been disregarded (Soros 1998a). These flaws can be summarized as follows (1) Banks engage in swaps, previous transactions, and derivative tacks among each other in addition to their exposure on their own balance sheetsbut these additional transactions do not take up in the banks balance sheets.So when Russian banks defaulted on their obligations to western banks, the western banks continued to owe their own clients. As these transactions form a daisy chain with many intermediaries, and each intermediary has an obligation to his/her counterparty, no simple way could be found to offset the obligations of one bank against another. As a result, many hedge and speculative funds sustained large losses, and had to be liquidated. This systemic failure led most market participants to reduce their exposure to emerging markets all around, and this caused bank stocks to plummet and global credit market to enter a crunch ph ase. 2) As individual countries attempt to prevent the exodus of capital from their economy by raising interest rates and placing chokes on foreign withdrawal of capital (as in Malaysia), this beggar-thy-neighbor policy tends to hurt the other countries that are exhausting to keep their capital markets open. (3) Another major factor working for the disintegration of the global capitalist system is the evident inability of the international monetary governance to hold it together The response of the G7 governments to the Russian crisis was woefully inadequate, and the loss of control was kind of scary.Financial markets are rather peculiar in this respect they resent any kind of government interference but they hold a vox populi deep down that if conditions get really rough the governance will step in. This belief has now been shaken (Soros 1998a). He alike adds that financial markets are inherently unstable. The global capitalist system is based on the belief that financial mar kets, left to their own devices, tend toward equilibriumThis belief is false (Soros 1998a). 3 His proposed cure is to reconsider the mission and methods of the IMF as well as fill again its capital base.Additionally, hed like to see the establishment of an world(prenominal) Credit Insurance Corporation to help create sound banking systems, which would be example to close supervision by the international credit agency, in developing countries (Soros 1998b). His last recommendation is to reconsider the functioning of debt-swap and derivative markets (Soros 1998b). Academia and Other Nongovernmental Organizations. Initially, capital of Minnesota Krugman, an economist at MIT, argued that problems with the Asian economies, combined with corruption and moral hazard, led to wild over-investment and a boom-bust cycle.More recently, however, Krugman explains that such weaknesses cannot explain the depth and severity of the crisis, nor the fact that it occurred in so many countries simulta neously, and instead he places the blame on financial panic and overly liberalized international and domestic financial systems (Radelet and Sachs 1999). According to Krugman, all short-term debt constitutes potential capital flight. The indispensability to fix structural problems in individual countries should not stand in the way of broader macroeconomic measures, in specific those designed to stimulate growth in hard times.He states that it is hard to avoid concluding that sooner or later we will have to address the clock at least part of the way back. To bound capital flows for countries that are unsuitable for either currency unions or free bungleing to bewilder financial markets to whatsoever extent and to seek low, but not too low, lump rather than price stability. We must heed the lessons of Depression economics, lest we be hale to relearn them the hard way (Uchitelle 1999). In other delivery, the global financial system is largely to blame for the recent crises. Fix the Countries Analysts IMF. According to the IMF, Russias financial crisis was brought on by a combination of (1) weak economic fundamentals, especially in the fiscal area (2) unfavorable developments in the external environment, including contagion effects from the Asian financial crisis and falling prices for key export commodities such as oil and (3) its vulnerability to changes in market sentiment arising from the financial support of balance of payments through short-term treasury bills and bonds placed on international markets (IMF December 1998).The IMF had pointed out in May 1998 that Russia had made insufficient progress in improving calculate procedures and tax systems, establishing competent agencies to collect taxes and control expenditures, clarifying intergovernmental fiscal relations, and ensuring transparency at all levels of government operations. By August 1998, investor confidence in the ability of Russian authorities to bring the fiscal system under control began to decline, immediately leading to the financial crisis, after the Duma failed to approve fiscal measures planned under the augmented Extended Fund Facility (EFF).These measures were aimed at reducing the fiscal deficit, implementing late structural reforms addressing the problem of arrears, promoting private orbit development, and reducing the vulnerability of the governments debt position, including a voluntary restructuring of treasury bills. 4 The extent to which the Russian crisis is attributable to contagion effects from the Asian crisis instead of to internal problems stemming from insufficient reforms in fiscal management is difficult to determine.According to the IMFs May 1998 assessment of spillover effects from the Asian crisis, Russias stock market was seriously hit by the crisis and by early spring 1998, stock prices in Russia had indeed not yet fully recovered from the lows reached in fall 1997. The Russian ruble had besides been hit hard and the central ban k had to step in heavily in the foreign exchange market just to keep the currency within the new exchange rate band.As international capital fled from the risky Asian economies in the fall and winter of 1997, investors who were similarly wary of risky investments in the regeneration economies began to reduce their exposure to Russian and other ENI markets. Nevertheless, emerging market investors quickly began to differentiate between high- and low-risk countries. By first quarter 1998 the Czech Republic and Poland had become relatively attractive to investors, receiving considerable short-term capital inflows and by January 1998 meter and Poors credit rating for Hungary had greatly improved.Russia and Ukraine, on the other hand, continued to suffer from structurally weak financial sectors and an over-dependence on short-term borrowing. To attract investment back into Russia, the Russian government had to raise interest rates in order to offer yields well above pre-crisis levels t o cover for the change magnitude perception of risk. As a result, foreign investment had started to flow back into Russia by early 1998.According to the IMF, differences in the severity of interest rate and fair-mindedness price movements among the transition countries illustrate the importance of appropriate domestic macroeconomic and structural policies to limit vulnerability to international financial crises. In Russia and Ukraine, financial sector weaknesses and a high dependence on government borrowing, in addition to chronic tax income problems, especially in Russias case, explain why these two countries were more unnatural by the Asian crisis than the Central and East European countries.In other words, the Asian crisis exposed Russias underlying structural problems and made the need to address them more apparent. The IMF continues to assert that the financial crisis in Russia was a crisis of the state. Nearly a year and a half ago, Michel Camdessus, Managing Director of t he IMF, claimed that the Russian state interferes in the economy where it shouldnt while where it should, it does nothing. Camdessus pointed out that the Russian state needs to make progress in promoting an efficient market economy through transparent and effective regulatory, legal, and tax systems. At present, the IMF still supports these recommendations (IMF November 1998). Existence of a Virtual Economy. Clifford Gaddy of the Brookings institution and Barry Ickes of Penn State University argue that although the immediate causes of Russias financial crisis are the large cypher deficit, resulting from nsufficient revenue collection, and an inability to service the debt, especially short-term dollar liabilities, there are more fundamental problems with Russias economy. These problems stem from illusions regarding prices, wages, taxes, and budgets that permeate the Russian economy to such a great extent that the economy has become realistic rather than actual. This realistic ec onomy 5 is derived from a public pretense that the economy is bigger and output more valuable than they really are.According to Gaddy and Ickes, the virtual economy primarily originated from the unreformed industrial sector inherited from the Soviet era, in which enterprises produced output that was sold via barter at prices that were higher than they would be if sold for cash. In general, these enterprises operate without paying their bills, as wages that should be paid to employees (but are not paid) become wage arrears, and required payments for inputs (which are also not paid) publish as interenterprise arrears and payments through barter.In fact, Gaddy and Ickes assert, people make an effort to avoid cash transactions because they would expose the pretense of the virtual economy. They go on to state that although the virtual economy acts as a safety net for Russian society, it has serious economic repercussions since it negatively affects enterprise restructuring, economic per formance measuring, and public sector reform (Gaddy and Ickes 1998). At this point, they argue that the West has two choices on how to help Russia.First, the West can concentrate on keeping Russia stable in the short term by bailing out the virtual economy, which will lead to nevertheless consolidation of a backward, noncompetitive economy and will guarantee the need for future emergency bailouts. The second option would be to refuse the bailout. The consequences of this option would be drasticthe ruble will lose its value, foreign capital will break awaybut on the positive side, the Russian economic policy that is so addicted to borrowing would have to kick the habit as it found its add on of international credit have sex off.They state that denying Russia a bailout is not without risks. But bailing out the virtual economy is sure to incr knack those risks for the future (Gaddy and Ickes 1998). U. S. Government. The U. S. Treasury section points out that despite the many impor tant reforms that have been carried out in Russiaincluding extensive privatization, price liberalization, and reduction of government consumptionreforms in a a couple of(prenominal) critical sectors have lagged behind, leading to the financial crisis.According to David Lipton, the principal problems include the failure to control the budget deficit and extensive government borrowing. The budget problems are a manifestation of the political struggle over the countrys economic direction and as long as these disputes over the proper role of government remain unresolved, he believes that budget difficulties and unnecessary government borrowing will continue unabated.He also argues that Russias high fiscal deficits have led to the countrys high interest rates since Russias macroeconomic problem is fundamentally fiscal interest rates are more decent viewed as a symptom of that problem, not a cause (Lipton 1998). Lastly, he argues that the failure to build a favorable investment climate and adhere to the regulation of law also helped to sow the seeds of the financial crisis (Lipton 1998). The Treasury Department also points to external factors that led to the crisis. According to Deputy Secretary Lawrence Summers, the Russian crisis was not inevitable.He avers that if the Asian crisis had not reduced confidence among emerging markets investors, and had the prices of export commodities (e. g. , oil) not fallen so dramaticallythe August 1998 crisis might not have taken place (Summers 1999). Nevertheless, the crisis did occur because the Russian government attempted to imitate an enormously risky course of simultaneously 6 devaluing the ruble, imposing a debt moratorium, and restructuring government bonds in response to the external pressures (Lipton 1998).To avoid future crises, Summers points out that Russia needs a tax system that supports the government and legitimizes enterprises, which probably involves a new allocation of spending and revenues between centr al and regional governments. Summers, however, is also quick to point out that it is much easier to talk about what tax reforms need to be implemented than to discuss how the reforms can be accepted politically. He adds that bank restructuring is another area where reform is needed and that it should be done in a fair nd transparent way within a legal framework that makes current owners take responsibility for their losses before scarce public funds are used (Summers 1999). Russian Government and Nongovernmental Analysts. Yegor Gaidar, former prime minister of Russia, attributes the crisis to the combined continuation of soft budget constraints from the socialist diaphragm along with the weakening of previous administrative controls and government corruption, which led to the bankruptcy of state enterprises.The early years of transition in Russia were marred by inefficient macroeconomic policy, weak budgetary and monetary constraints, and inflation that eroded budget revenues. Alth ough later macroeconomic policy was more efficient and succeeded in controlling inflation, efforts to improve revenue collection or cut expenditure obligations have failed, leading to unsustainable deficits.The lessons learned here are that budget deficits should be reduced as quickly as possible, as inflation is also controlled, and the vulnerability of exchange rate regimes to potential crises should be addressed immediately (IMF 1999 Gaidar 1999). In terms of the current regime, Gaidar describes Primakov and his government as a commie government in post-communist Russia, because Primakov and his cabinet come from the traditional Soviet economics establishment and his post-crisis approach relies on strengthening and centralizing government control.According to Gaidar, the Russian government faced two possible paths to solve the crisis (1) return to the approach employed in 199294, with soft monetary and budget policies, or (2) maintain a tight monetary policy, stabilize the ruble, and carry out fundamental budget reforms to allow the government to balance revenues and expenditures. The first path would lead to the return of high inflation rates, as the government relaxed its control over the funds supply in an attempt to pay its debts, but the banks would benefit from the return of cheap money issued by the Central Bank.The second path would involve speeding up structural reforms, which would be good news for profitable enterprises but would mean torturesome consequences for unproductive enterprisesmostly firms in the industrial and financial sectorsas they would be allowed to go bankrupt if they could not compete in world markets. Both paths would be painful, Gaidar explains, but the first path of high inflation would also be inequitable, as the poorest layer of society tends to suffer most from increasing prices.Not surprisingly, Primakov chose to pursue a modified version of the inflationary approach, a sort of populist economics policy that had been im plemented in many Latin American countries. The causal agency Primakov opted for this path, as Gaidar states, is because in part, the lack of internal and external sources for financial support after the 7 dismissal of the Kiriyenko government pushed the Primakov government toward choosing the inflationary variant (Institute for stintings in passage 1999).Andrei Illarionov, Director of the Institute for Economic Analysis in Moscow, while noting the IMFs successes with respect to Russia, criticized the IMF for being too willing to compromise on Russian conditionality. Not one of the IMF programs developed in Russia, Illarionov claims, has been executed in full, as a result of the softening and revision of conditions in original agreements. He states that decisions to provide financing for Russia, motivated by political rather than economic considerations, have given rise to the problem of moral hazard. As a result, the Russian government became forged after being granted unearned financial assistance, and policy became even more irresponsible than before (Illarionov 1998). final examinationly, Illarionov also criticizes the IMF for offering inappropriate policy recommendations to Russian authorities in two other areas exchange rate and fiscal policies. The IMF program (mid-1998, pre-crisis) stipulated that the exchange rate policy should remain unchanged for the remainder of 1998, in order to preserve the low inflation rates, and prescribed that the Russian government should concentrate mainly on raising revenue rather than reducing expenditures.Although many poor 9 O c t 9 8 J u l 9 8 A p r 9 8 egaw muminim laiciffo J a n 9 8 O c t 9 7 .9991/20 ,PECER ecruoS J u l 9 7 A p r 9 7 J a n 9 7 Dissatisfaction over the continuing problem of wage arrears led to an increase in strikes throughout the country toward the latter part of 1998 1873 strikes were registered in December 1998, some 3. 4 times the figure of speech during the previous December. aissuR ni ec netsisbuS dna ,snoisneP ,segaW ecnetsisbus woleb era % 92 level ecnetsisbus laiciffo ecnetsisbus woleb era % 12 0 001 002 003 004 005 006 007 008 R u bl e s p e r m o n t h . eople have become poorer, the impoverishing effects of the crisis have also hit other groups within Russian society. Workers involved in the business of merchandising trade goods have found that demand for their products has nearly evaporated as not only consumer incomes have fallen, but also ruble depreciation means higher prices on imports. As a result, many of these trade businesses have shed labor or closed. One of the longer-term consequences of the economic crisis in Russia may be the strain on society, which is likely to weaken the Russian governments ability to continue to push for reforms.In some ENI countries, the crisis has given reform skeptics an excuse to abandon or reverse some reforms already implemented. The social pressure against further economic reforms, now seen by many as the cause rather than the cure for the economic crises, may become strong enough to counter-balance the pro-reform force. It may lead some ENI countries to get stuck in what Adrian Karatnycky describes as a state of stasis rather than of transition. Stability Versus Democracy Politically, the financial collapse has weakened Russia vis-a-vis the west, but its relative power in the region has in many ways increased.Not only has the crisis given Moscow an excuse to consolidate power over the regions throughout Russia, but it has also allowed many hard-liners within Russia to gain some ground in their push to reassert Russias traditional sphere of influence. In addition, many neighboring regions have found themselves with large arrears on their payments to Russia for natural gas deliveries, and have had to strike deals with Russia to find ways to settle these debts through deliveries of victuals and other barter arrangements.Following the onset of the crisis in August, the Russian government proposed many changes intended to promote economic stability at the cost of democracy. In February 1999, Prime Minister Primakov argued that Russias governors should be name by the professorship, rather than elected by their constituents, so that Moscow can take back control over the regions and avoid a collapse of the country. President of Belarus Alyaksandr Lukashenko rejoiced in the crumbling of IMF-backed reforms in Russia, considering the crisis to be a indication of his position in favor of state planning and price controls. The old proposal regarding a possible political union of Belarus, Ukraine, and Russia has also resurfaced, as Russia and some neighboring countries have concluded that further integration will help solve their problems. In the words of Ivan Rybkin, President Yeltsins envoy to the CIS, the recent crisis taught us all that we must stand together in order to survive (Rutland 1999).Effects on live Countries The drop in real wages in Russiacoupled with the devaluatio n of the rublehas translated into dramatically reduced Russian imports. For the neighboring countries that depend on Russia as a market for their exports, the shrinking market in Russia has been disastrous for their local economies. As Russians are shifting consumption away from the relatively more expensive imported goods, the producers of these goods in neighboring countries are faced 10 with a dramatic fall in demand for their products.This has translated into falling output and increased unemployment for the countries that are most closely tied to Russia through trade, especially Moldova (more than 50 share of Moldovan exports go to Russia) Belarus, Ukraine, and Kazakhstan, (gt33 percent of exports to Russia, as of early 1998) and Georgia (gt30 percent of exports to Russia) (EC 1999). The drop in remittances from nationals living in Russia has led to decreased incomes in neighboring countries with large numbers of gastarbeiter working in Russia. Armenia, Georgia, and Azerbaijan have been most earnestly hit by this decline in remittances.In some cases the pattern seems to have been reversed, with families in neighboring countries now supporting relatives living in Russia (EC 1999). Finally, food prices have also increased in the neighboring countries of the NIS, as the cost of imports from outside Russia has risen as a consequence of the significant devaluation of local currencies. any(prenominal) of the specific effects and impacts on other NIS and neighboring countries are summarized briefly below. ArmeniaAccumulation of public sector arrears is likely, as government is facing difficulties in financing of education, health care, and other expenditures.Remittances from Armenians in Russia have decreased, placing additional pressure on family support systems, and this could result in increased poverty. AzerbaijanTrade-related consequences in the short term are less than for other NIS countries, as the political instability in the North Caucasus region ha s already limited trade ties with Russia prior to the crisis. Government spending was cut in 1998, and further cuts in 1999 will affect key social sectors. As in other Caucasus countries, decreased remittances from Azerbaijani nationals residing in Russia has reduced family incomes in Azerbaijan.Baltic RegionEstonia, Latvia, and LithuaniaThe Russian crisis forced some Baltic banks to fail, and several others to reveal their under-reporting of exposure to Russia in their September 1998 quarterly reports. Better developed financial systems, a reorientation toward western markets, and general political stability have helped to limit the damage and contagion effects from the Russian crisis. BelarusOne of the most affected countries in the NIS, Belarus was highly dependent on trade with Russia prior to the crisis. Exports to Russia plunged from $400 million/month in the first half of 1998 to just $170 million/month by September 1998.Shortages of basic foods forced the government to get into rationing. GeorgiaThe Russian market accounted for 30 percent of Georgias exports prior to the crisis, and Georgian nationals living in Russia provided a significant amount of income to Georgian families through remittances. The trade deficit with Russia widened to 50 percent in October 1998, forcing the Georgian authorities to float the lari (which led to a sharp depreciation). 11 KazakhstanIn the first half of 1998, half of Kazakhstans exports went to Russia, and the impact of the crisis has been felt in Kazakhstan primarily through the reduction of exports to Russia.Kazakhstan introduced a temporary ban on the import of some Russian foodstuffs, in order to control the inflow of cheapened Russian goods by-line the depreciation of the ruble. KyrgyzstanNearly 60 percent of Kyrgyzstans exports went to Russia, prior to the crisis, so this country was also one of the more vulnerable to negative shocks through the trade mechanism. In this most pro-reform of the Central Asian Repub lics, price liberalization of utilities and privatization may be threatened, as consumers are less able to pay the higher tariffs as a esult of fallen incomes. MoldovaTrade with Russia is important to Moldova, as 50 percent of Moldovan exports went to Russia prior to the crisis. Many farms and other agro-exporters have been unable to pay wages, as their export market has dried up in Russia. Here, too, the crisis has threatened the reform and liberalization process implemented by the government, as investors interest in the Moldovan economy has diminished and a heavy withdrawal from commercial banks have signaled a lack of confidence in this country.TajikistanLow commodity prices for cotton and metallic had already damaged the Tajikistan economy before the Russian crisis, and the fragile peace held together in part with the support of the Russian military (serving as confine guards) has certainly not gained strength from the crisis. Apparently, Tajikistan is not as dependent on tra de with Russia as other NIS countries, and this has helped to insulate Tajikistan from the direct effects of the crisis. TurkmenistanExposure of Turkmen banks to Russian markets has been limited, as the Turkmenistan economy is tightly controlled by the state.The Russian crisis therefore is not expected to have a strong direct impact on Turkmenistan. UkraineClosely linked to Russia through trade and financial ties, Ukraine has suffered greatly as a result of the Russian crisis. The hryvnia lost half its value against the dollar future(a) the crisis, and reserves have fallen (as of early 1999) to only one month of imports. Inflation surged to 12. 8 percent in October 1998 alone, following a long period of relatively stable inflation before the onset of the crisis (2 percent inflation in first half of 1998).UzbekistanAs Uzbekistan has been gradually reorienting its international trade visibility away from Russia over recent years, the country has apparently been less affected by the c risis than other NIS countries. Further, the underdeveloped banking system and financial markets in Uzbekistan may have helped to insulate that country from the shocks emanating from Russia in August 1998, as Uzbekistan had relatively little exposure to Russias financial markets. 2 Proposed Remedies As discussed throughout this paper, two camps have emerged in academic and policy circles that seek to explain the causes of and remedies for the Russian financial crisis. This section highlights some of the remedies proposed by each camp. According to the fix the countries critics, such as the IMF and the U. S. Treasury Department, the Russian government must continue pushing for reforms in the public finance and banking sectors.According to Gaddy and Ickes, only two options exist for western creditors and international financial institutions keep Russia stable in the short-term by bailing out the virtual economy or refusing a bailout. Denying Russia a bailout would have negative effect s in the short-term by leading to the demise of large commercial banks and oligarchs, foreign capital flight, and currency devaluation. In the long run, however, Gaddy and Ickes prefer this option because they believe it will force Russia to adjust to economic life without a steady supply of credit available and adapt sound economic policies.They dislike the first option simply because they believe it will lead to the further development of a nonmarket-oriented economy that would require bailouts in the future. The Treasury Department adds that bank restructuring and reforms in tax administration and collection are necessary as well. The fix the global financial system critics, such as Jeff Sachs and George Soros, urge that the international financial system be reformed so that short-term borrowing by banks and governments be limited so as to avoid potential investor panics.In addition, Sachs recommends that domestic banking regulations, in the form of enhanced capital adequacy stan dards and policies that encourage partial bank-sector ownership by foreign capital, be implemented in order to limit vulnerability of the domestic economy to foreign creditor panics, and that exchange rates be kept flexible instead of pegged. In addition to these proposed remedies, others have gone further to propose mechanisms for recovering losses (Sexton 1998). According to Sexton, foreign creditors have at their disposal four mechanisms to recover losses to Russian firms 1.Convertible debt securities debitors could issue convertible security bonds to creditors although Sexton argues that this probably wont work too well in Russia 2. Treasury or redeemed shares company may exchange its own shares, that were bought back, or interests to extinguish outstanding indebtedness there should be no tax consequences to debtor on repurchase of shares on resale to foreign creditor, debtor should be taxed on any gain on shares or should be able to deduct any loss sustained 3.Alternative deb t refinancing structure swapping debt for convertible debt which creditor converts into equity issue by debtor to creditor of convertible bonds as a means of refinancing outstanding debt creditor should make sure conversion ratio covers value of outstanding debt over term of loan disadvantage to this 13 strategy is that creditor is refinancing and likely to have twice the outstanding debt for some time 4.Securitizing the debt convert debt into security which creditor then contributes to debtors charter capital to pay for the shares (key issue facing creditors thinking of taking equity in a Russian debtor company in exchange for indebtedness is how to value that equity) Summary This paper has addressed the opposing views as to the causes of and remedies for the Russian financial crisis. Two central camps have emerged.One camp argues that the Russian economy has severe structural problems that were the primary cause of the crisis fiscal deficit, banking sector problems. The other gro up points to the IMF and the problems with the international financial system, claiming that moral hazard problems led investors to underestimate the risk of investing in emerging markets such as Russia, and that unregulated short-term investment flows out of emerging markets can result from the panic. individually of these groups proposes different remedies for the crisis, based on their assessment of the roots of the crisis. The IMF and Treasury Department insist that the Russian government continue to push for reforms in public finance and the banking sector, claiming that weaknesses in these areas ultimately led to the onset of the Russian crisis.Jeffrey Sachs, George Soros, and others who are critical of the international financial systems and the role of the IMF in the recent financial crises, recommend that the short-term borrowing by governments and banks in emerging markets be limited and regulated, and that exchange rates are flexible rather than pegged. Although the wors t of the Russian crisis may have already passed, as the Russian and other ENI stock markets appear to have recovered and the dramatic fall in production has been reversed, the original causes of the crisis still need to be addressed.Continued progress in banking and fiscal reforms in Russia will be necessary to ensure that the country is less vulnerable to future external shocks and foreign creditor panics. Improvements in these sectors would help restore investor confidence in the Russian economy and reverse the current outflow of capital. 14 ANNEX What Happened in Russia? A Brief Chronology of Events Asian Crisis Precursor to the Russian Crisis July 1997, Thailanddevaluation of Thai baht December 1997, Koreadevaluation of Korean won ate October 1997 Pressure on ruble intensifies, as result of Asian crisis December 1997Foreign exchange pressure temporarily recedes in Russia 19 December 1997Standard and Poors Sovereign Ratings of Russian ruble longtermBB- outlooknegative short-termB January 1998Reemerging pressure on ruble forces Central Bank to raise interest rates, increase reserve requirements on foreign exchange deposits, and intervene on ruble and treasury bill market March 1998Stock market prices in Russia have not yet recovered from lows reached in late fall 1997 May 1998Russia places major commercial bank under Central Bank administration miners strike over wage arrears Russia continues to intervene on foreign exchange markets to support ruble, but investors increasingly see this strategy as unsustainable Late May 1998Interest rates in Russia increased to 150 percent Russian government announces revisions to 1998 budget, including 20 percent cut in expenditures and new initiatives to boost revenues aboriginal June 1998Recent policy announcements temporarily ease tensions, allow partial reversal of earlier interest rate hikes 9 June 1998Standard and Poors Sovereign Ratings of Russian ruble long-term B+ outlookstable short-termB Late June 19 98Russian authorities unveil anti-crisis program, aimed at boosting tax revenues, cutting expenditures, and speeding up structural reforms . 9991 lirp A , eci vre S et aR egn ahc xE CIFI C AP ecruo S 15 4 / 2 / 9 9 3 / 2 / 9 9 2 / 2 / 9 9 1 / 2 / 9 9 1 2 / 2 / 9 8 1 1 / 2 / 9 8 1 0 / 2 / 9 8 9 / 2 / 9 8 8 / 2 / 9 8 7 / 2 / 9 8 6 / 2 / 9 8 5 / 2 / 9 8 4 / 2 / 9 8 3 / 2 / 9 8 2 / 2 / 9 8 1 / 2 / 9 8 03 Russian Crisis Timeline 0 5 01 51 02 52 After the devaluation of the Thai baht in July 1997, one Asian country after another had to raise interest rates sharply to avoid currency devaluation. But the combination of high interest rates and currency depreciation, which inflated the burden of foreign debt, provoked a financial crisis (Krugman 1999).SU$/selbuR etaR egnahcxE elbuR 16 1 2 / 2 0 / 9 8 9 / 2 0 / 9 8 6 / 2 0 / 9 8 3 / 2 0 / 9 8 1 2 / 2 0 / 9 7 9 / 2 0 / 9 7 6 / 2 0 / 9 7 3 / 2 0 / 9 7 1 2 / 2 0 / 9 6 .9991 lirpA ,semiT wocsoM ecruoS 9 / 2 0 / 9 6 6 / 2 0 / 9 6 3 / 2 0 / 9 6 1 2 / 2 0 / 9 5 9 / 2 0 / 9 5 6 / 2 0 / 9 5 3 / 2 0 / 9 5 1 2 / 2 0 / 9 4 9 / 2 0 / 9 4 6 / 2 0 / 9 4 0 003 xednI semiT wocsoM egnahcxE kcotS naissuR Mid-July 1998Russian authorities introduce additional policy package, in the context of an IMF agreement on an augmented Extended Fund Facility (EFF) arrangement 20 July 1998IMF releases first $4. 8 billion tranche of $22. billion extra credit pledge, as policy package is approved by IMF Late July 1998Initial effects of this package are positive, with equity prices rebounding 30 percent, treasury bill rates falling from 100 to 50 percent, and a lowering of the Central Bank refinancing rate from 80 to 60 percent Early August 1998The Duma fails to approve new reform program President forced to veto several Duma measures and introduce others by decree 13 August 1998Standard and Poors Sovereign Ratings of Russian ruble longtermB- outlooknegative short-termC 14 August 1998Average treasury bill rates are about 300 percent, inter national reserves down to only $15 billion, and Russian banks are unable to meet payment obligationsRussia on the verge of full-scale banking and currency crisis 15 August 1998Boris Yeltsin announces that there will be no devaluation of the ruble 17 August 1998Russian government defaults on GKO Treasury Bonds, imposes 90day moratorium on foreign debt payments, abandons ruble exchange rate corridor 17 August 1998Standard and Poors Sovereign Ratings of Russian ruble downgraded long-termCCC outlooknegative short-termC 21 August 1998Russias international reserves fall to $13. 5 billion, after renewed heavy preventative in an effort to support the weakened ruble 26 August 1998Following heavy intervention, the Russian Central Bank announces that it will stop selling U. S. ollars, and suspends trading of ruble on main exchanges Late August 1998Kiriyenko government is dissolved, financial crisis intensifies 1 September 1998Russia is the IMFs largest borrower, with a combined total of attr ibute at this date equal to nearly $18. 8 billion 2 September 1998Russian Central Bank abandons exchange rate band, lets the ruble float 16 September 1998Standard and Poors Sovereign Ratings of Russian ruble longtermCCC- lowest possible S and P rating outlooknegative short-termC January 1999Moodys assesses financial strength (E) and credit ratings (Ca) of the Russian banks at the lowest possible levels most banks are insolvent (or nearly so) 005 054 004 053 052 002 051 001 05 15 January 1999The Central Bank of Russia re-launches trading on the domestic debt market.The new securities are to be used in the restructuring of frozen GKO and other debt instruments 27 January 1999Standard and Poors Sovereign Ratings of Russian ruble LongtermSelective Default outlookNot Meaningful short-termSelective Default 5 February 1999The 1999 budget was passed by the Duma in its fourth and final reading. The budget estimates a 2. 5 percent budget deficit, and assumes that the government will receiv e $7 billion in external loans to help finance foreign debt service 17 BIBLIOGRAPHY European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD). March 1999. Overview on Developments in the Operating Environment, mimeo. European Commission (EC). 20 January 1998. The Russian Crisis and Its Impact on the New freelancer States and Mongolia. Communication of the European Commission to the Council and the European Parliament. http//europa. eu. int/comm/dg1a/nis/russian_crisis_impact/1. htm Frankel, Jeffrey A. 1999. Soros Split Personality Scanty Proposals from the Financial Wizard. Foreign Affairs 78 (2) 124-130. Gaddy, Clifford G. , and Barry W. Ickes. 1998. Russias Virtual Economy. Foreign Affairs 77 (5) 53-67. Gaidar, Yegor. February 1999. Lessons of the Russian Crisis for Transition Economies. Institute for Economies in Transition on-line publication. Illarionov, Andrei. 1998. Russia and the IMF, testimony prepared for hearing of the General Oversight and Investigations Subcommittee of the Banking and Financial Services Committee of the U. S. House of Representatives, 10 September. International Monetary Fund (IMF). 1999. IMF Survey. Volume 28, Number 4.International Monetary Fund. May 1998 and December 1998. World Economic Outlook. International Research and Exchange Board (IREX). 1998. Russias Economic Crisis and Its Effect on the New Independent States, a discussion report summarizing conclusions of an IREX policy forum held on 18 November. Kommunisticheskie pravitelstvo v postkommunisticheskoi Rossii pervye itogi i vozmozhnye perspektivy Communist Government in Post-Communist Russia Initial Results and Possible Perspectives. 1999. Working publisher Series. Moscow Institut ekonomiki perekhodnogo perioda Institute for Economies in Transition. Krugman, Paul. 1999. The Return of Depression Economics. Foreign Affairs 78 (1) 5674. Lipton, David. 1998. Treasury Undersecretary David Lipton Testimony Before the House Banking General Oversight and Investigations Su bcommittee on Russia, RR-2673, 10 September. Odling-Smee, John. 1998. The IMF Responds on Russia A Letter to the Editor, 30 November. 18 OBrien, Timothy. 1998. George Soros Has Seen the Enemy. It Looks Like Him. The New York Times, 6 December . Phillips, Michael M. 1999. Apocalypse? No. Round the Globe, Signs Point to Final Days of Financial Crisis. The Wall Street Journal, 14 April . Radelet, Steven, and Jeffrey Sachs. 1999. What Have We Learned, So Far, From the Asian Financial Crisis? Paper sponsored by USAID/G/EGAD under Consulting Assistance on Economic Reform (CAER) II Project. Robinson, Anthony. 1999. Russia Coming in from the Cold. The Banker 149 (877) 4849. Russian European Centre for Economic Policy (RECEP). 1999. Russian Economic Trends. Monthly Update, 10 February. Russian Market Research Company (RMRC). 1998. Business Barometer Survey Moscow, October 2-3, 1998, published on the American Chamber of Commerce in Russia website. Rutland, Peter. 1999. Moscow Casts a Long Shadow. Transitions 6 (3) 27-31. Sexton, Robert. 1999. Turning Russian Debt into Equity. Euromoney no. 357 75-76. Smirnov, Mikhail. 1998. Rubl kaput ili kak bank Rossii opustil rubl The Ruble is Kaput, or, How the Bank of Russia Lost the Ruble, Nationalnaia sluzhba novostei National News Service. Soros, George. 1998a. Testimony to the Congressional Committee on Banking and Financial Services of the U. S. House of Representatives, 15 September. Soros, George. 1998b. The Crisis of Global Capitalism Open Society Endangered, remarks before the Council on Foreign Relations, New York, 10 December. Summers, Lawrence H. 1999. Russian and the United States The Economic Agenda, remarks by Deputy Treasury Secretary Lawrence H. Summers at the U. S. -Russian Investment Symposium in Cambridge, MA, 14 January. Uchitelle, Louis. 1999. Crash Course Just Whats Driving the Crisis in emerge Markets? The New York Times, 29 January . 19

No comments:

Post a Comment

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.